Dumbing Down in Canberra - A Guide to the Public Service Reform Industry (Part 2)


On the menus of some delicatessens and outdoor eateries can be found the "ploughman's lunch" - a rich meal of cheese, bread and eggs, often topped off by sundried tomatoes or olives. It's a filling meal, generally inappropriate for people with a sedentary lifestyle. And, contrary to the bucolic notion that one is sharing in the simple fare of a ploughman, there is no evidence that it bears any relationship to what ploughmen ever had for lunch.

So too it is with public sector "reforms". The basis of many of these reforms is that the public sector should emulate the private sector, to the point of creating fictitious private sector models for emulation. By applying these fictitious models, public sector managers can inhabit the world of the make-believe private sector. Just as the urban middle class can pretend they are sharing in the world of the ploughmen, so too can public servants inhabit a fantasy private sector world. They can be transformed from bureaucrats to entrepreneurs.

Emulation of the private sector, or of an imaginary private sector, lies at the heart of recent public sector "reforms". There are two assumptions; one is that the private sector is intrinsically more efficient than the public sector, and the other is that there is one, clear set of private practices.

But, as we have shown in the first of these two articles, there are certain things that can be done only on the public sector, and certain other things that the private sector can do but not as well as the public sector - situations of market failure. And the notion of a private sector ideal is naive. There is no one "private sector" model - covering operations from sandwich shops through to steel mills, from operating call centres through to designing software systems. And similarly there should be no one "public sector" model, covering operations from a pre-school through to a power utility, or from a local government aged care centre through to the Commonwealth Treasury. Yet, the path of "reform" has tried to fit one normative model on the public sector - a model which, like the ploughman's lunch, has little connection to its claimed origins.

Many of the "reforms" can be understood in this light - naive attempts to mimic what some believe to be "private sector" practice.

The bottom line

The most pervasive of such developments is the primacy of the budget "bottom line". The most important measure of any program is the budgetary outcome. Producing impressive budgetary figures has become more important than the task of economic management. We covered the macro aspects of this in the first of these two articles, but this budgetary obsession has implications at a micro level for the day-to-day management of public sector agencies. The guiding notion is that because the private sector is driven by bottom line performance, then also should the public sector be so driven.

Fortunately the bottom line obsession is not universal in the private sector. But, from time to time, we see the entrepreneur who, in order to make an impression on the financial markets, goes all out to create an impressive set of financial ratios - a task easily achieved by letting maintenance expenditure slip, by reducing quality, by exploiting trust and goodwill with customers and employees, by reducing "soft" investments in marketing, research and human capital and by engaging in a little creative accounting. To show a good short term cash flow there are many clever options, such as selling assets and leasing them back. These devices can fool the financial markets for a year or two, but are ultimately at the expense of long term corporate health.

So too it is with the public sector. If producing impressive budgetary figures were an end in itself, then the task of public administration would be easy; spend less and find any way to raise revenue. But to make the "bottom line" a policy objective in its own right is absurd, for it glosses over the basic conflict between financial management and economic management, which can often be in conflict. In adopting a narrow financial focus such as the deficit or the "size" of government, serious economic damage can result.

Financial management is about managing budgets. Financial accounting is no more than a pallid representation of a program's full costs and benefits. It is limited by what accountants call the "money measurement" concept; that is, financial accounting data measures only what passes through an agency's ledger. Economic management, however, is far broader, particularly in the public sector. It is about creating wealth for the community, in ways which generally do not pass through any ledger. There is no ledger which captures the value of public health, safe roads, clean waterways or an educated population. These values can be partially captured in cost-benefit analysis, but not in financial accounting figures.

Despite these known limitations, financial accounting is in the ascendency in the Commonwealth, displacing the more inclusive disciplines of cost-benefit analysis and considerations of public good theory. There is a process of false simplification, or dumbing down, in the accounting reforms being introduced in the name of accrual accounting and accrual budgeting. Accrual accounting is certainly an improvement on the old cash accounting system it replaces. But it is being vested with false expectations and magical powers. Public servants are told they can use accrual accounting to determine the full cost of their agencies' activities, with statements such as:

"Accrual information also enables the full costs of an organization's operations and activities to be measured."(1)

and

"Accrual accounting will provide ...a clear picture of the full cost of the goods and services our agencies provide".(2)

Such statements are dangerously simplistic. They reveal a fundamental ignorance in that they vest too much credibility into financial accounting.

No well-managed firm would make such an error. In the private sector there is a clear distinction between financial accounting, which is about external accountability, and management accounting, which is about costing and decision making. Costing and decision-making has to be undertaken using a variety of skills and judgement; there is no accounting system or computer program which can reveal a "full cost". This point is stressed by accounting professionals such as Harvard's Robert Kaplan, who has waned on the dangers of managerial accounting being supplanted by the mechanistic discipline of financial accounting.(3) Yet the public service, in all its managerial reforms, is ignoring the discipline of management accounting, and its public policy equivalent, cost-benefit analysis, which brings to bear those costs which do not pass through the ledger.

Because of the money measurement convention, the costs revealed by financial accounting are very limited. They do not take into account non-market costs. A decision not to spend public money on upgrading a road or railroad may look like a financial saving, but it will impose social costs in terms of travel time. Saving on public pharmaceutical expenditure by removing drugs from the Pharmaceutical Benefits Scheme will look good in the ledger of the health department, but it may result in a large shift in costs to the poorest members of society. A decision to charge a high price for a government publication may look good for the Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics, but if it results in farmers finding commodity and market information is unaffordable, it will have costly consequences for the farm sector, quite out of proportion to the small amount of revenue raised from charging for the publication.

As pointed out in the first article, many activities are in the public sector because of market failure. That is, because the private sector would not provide those services, or, if it did, would not provide them efficiently. For example, the private sector, left to its own devices, generally won't provide public health services, for there is no way in which the beneficiaries can pay a private provider for these services. The private sector will under-provide goods with high external benefits, such as research, and it tends to under-provide goods with long term returns, such as education and environmental protection. These (and many more instances) are cases of what economists call "market failure", and it is the economics of market failure which should form the prime guide to the public/private split of activities in a modern economy. If a public agency could be managed along purely private sector lines, in fact, there is probably little justification for it being in the public sector.

Why has such bad practice come about? One can answer simply that it's the ideology of neoliberalism, but that's a superficial explanation. More likely, it's because Australia lacks a well-understood and agreed notion of the role of the public sector. Most people know that somehow the government has to be involved in defence and welfare, and that the government need not be involved in market activities like tourist accommodation and retailing. But even people with a degree in economics are not necessarily exposed to the economics of market failure.

One can do an entire major in economics without having to depart from the assumptions of a well-functioning, competitive market. When commentators like Michael Pusey criticize the dominance of economics in public policy, they are really criticizing the paucity of economic thought and education in Australian universities, particularly in relation to the economics of the public sector.(4)

Australia has no institution like France's Ecole Nationale D'Administration, which can develop a set of professional public service skills and knowledge. Nor are university postgraduate courses in public administration well patronized. For most students, particularly those with numerical ability, the MBA (Master of Business Administration) is a much more attractive option than the MPA (Master of Public Administration), and the MPA is usually centered on "soft" disciplines, such as the personnel management (under the neologism "human resource management"). Most financial management training for the public sector is about financial accounting, rather than management accounting, and cost-benefit analysis is relegated to obscurity as a highly specialized discipline. Tony Harris, former Auditor General in NSW, found that private firms were able to exploit the public sector, because public servants were not equipped with the financial training to analyze contracting out, BOOT (build, own, operate and transfer) and leaseback proposals.(5) The capacity to do such analysis is standard fare in an MBA course, but not in MPA courses. Just as loan sharks target the naive and poorly educated consumers, so to do their corporate equivalents find public servants an easy target for schemes which exploit the public purse.

Managerialism

"Let the managers manage" was the motto of the mid eighties reforms. If managers could be freed from constraints imposed by unnecessary regulations, such as control on inputs, line item budgets (which meticulously specified what was to be spent on salaries, overtime, travel, communications etc), and staff ceilings, they would be able to exercise their creative talents to improve the efficiency of their operations.

The designers of the Financial Management Improvement Program in the mid eighties and subsequent reforms, without necessarily being aware of the source of their ideas, drew on a private sector management practice known as "Management by Objectives" (MBO), first described by Peter Drucker in 1954.(6) A key aspect of MBO is that management exists in a hierarchy of objectives - higher level managers have general, high level objectives, which get broken down into simpler objectives down the line. Each manager is given specific objectives, and doesn't have to worry about the wider implications.

MBO works very well where the work of a number of units comes together to form a unified whole. It is a good way to organize an automobile factory or a hamburger chain. In public administration, however, its uses are limited, for it tends to encourage parochialism and cost-shifting. The manager in a strict MBO environment has a confined, narrow focus. (Drucker himself was later to warn of the dangers of unthinking applications of management techniques in the public sector.(7))

Most public sector agencies are not stand-alone. A key characteristic of the public sector is interactive complexity and interconnectivity. What happens in one part will affect other parts. For example, although employment programs, superannuation policy and tax collection are handled in separate agencies, decisions made in one of these agencies will have effects in the other agencies. Trade and agricultural policies are inextricably woven together, but for administrative convenience they are handled in separate agencies. The public sector needs a large amount of coordination, and people, at all levels, who understand system complexity and who can see the big picture. Alistair Mant describes system complexity using the colourful metaphor of the frog and the bicycle.(8) One can bring a bicycle to optimum performance by attending to its parts; what one does to the chain sprocket is largely independent of what one does to the front wheel bearing. But one cannot do the same to a frog, which is a complete, complex, interconnected organism. Mant provides several examples, mainly from the UK public sector, in which managers, looking after their own defined areas of responsibility, caused huge damage to wider systems. That is why there is merit in what is known as a "career public service", in which people at all levels in all agencies have some knowledge of the broad context of public administration.

There was a time when the public service was looked upon as a career service in its own right. Indeed, that was the philosophy behind the 1853 Northcote-Trevelyan Report, a manifesto for the UK and colonial bureaucracies, including Australia's. One of the key planks was that the service should be organized "as a single service, and not as a disintegrated, fragmentary service".(9) Up to the 1990s there were vestiges of this philosophy in Australia, with practices such as graduate recruitment to the service as a whole, management training which relied on mobility between agencies (and the private sector) and standardized classifications across agencies. Now the service is truly fragmented. Mobility between agencies has fallen, and what mobility remains is mainly among technical service staff rather than policy staff.(10) Staff are employed under enterprise agreements with individual agencies (a situation which resulted in confusion in the administrative rearrangements following the 1998 election). Tenure of service was one of the casualties of the reforms.

Contrary to the view that insecurity prods people to performance, there is a strong case for vesting the public service with a degree of stability, as a counter to an intrinsically unstable political set of institutions. No private company would survive for long if it were faced with a hostile takeover bid every three years, and possibly more often. The public service should provide a source of ongoing expert and dispassionate advice. (Elected government is under no obligation to heed such advice, however.) Prime Minister Menzies considered a professional, politically detached public service as an administrative asset.(11)

Notions of professionalism, stability and tenure, however, are now seen as part of an old order. The new public servant is an entrepreneur, not an analyst. He or she is responsive to two prime demands - the political demands of executive government, and the budgetary demands of the Department of Finance and Administration. While elder statesmen like Robert Menzies and respected academics like Alan Blinder and Robert Reich may defend the notion of a professional bureaucracy, the fashion is in the opposite direction.(12) Admittedly, tenure in the public service was abused in the old system - it was used to support featherbedding, and the public service carried many unproductive staff. But such abuse establishes a case for reforming tenure, not abolishing it.

The other trend has been the politicization of the public service. Public servants have always had a close interface with executive government, but the public would be shocked if ever they knew how much work of public servants is spent on providing political services to executive government - drafting replies to constituents, writing speeches, and writing briefs to protect ministers from Opposition criticism. As the experiences with the Coalition's pre-election tax proposals demonstrated in 1998, the public service can easily become a political secretariat for the governing party.

In losing a professional and disinterested public service we lose our only long term, stable source of disinterested advice on public policy. Governments have many sources of advice - lobbyists, backbenchers, and party apparatchicks, but all come with a strong vested interest, and, in general, they represent the voices of concentrated interests rather than the community as a whole - investors and workers in particular industries, electors in marginal seats. As Mancur Olson points out, reliance on such sources of advice can stultify governments into a role limited to intermediation between specific interest groups, at the expense of the wider public purpose.(13) A professional public service can act as a counter to this concentration of influence, by representing, dispassionately, the interests of the many and the weak, and to bring those voices to the political table.(14) From such processes can come more inclusive and economically responsible public policy.

Measures and incentives

Along with MBO has come a plethora of performance measures. While the management texts warn about the risk of MBO producing its own paperwork burden, the public service seems to be deaf to such warnings. The "reform" industry has become in itself a large, unaccounted, bureaucratic overhead. One public servant describes the process as akin to "pulling up a sapling every month to see how it's growing". John Micklethwait and Adrian Wooldridge, writers for The Economist describe the performance obsession:

Mention Management theory to Oxford professors who spend half their time reporting back to Whitehall or to doctors who are judged by how many 'illness episodes' they have treated and you are greeted by a tirade. Everybody in the upper reaches of the public sector seems to agree on the awfulness of managers: on the hideousness of their language, the harmfulness of their methods, and the sheer second-rateness of their intellects. The only question is why governments have allowed themselves to be hoodwinked by this bunch of failed businessmen into wasting so much money.(15)

One of the genuine reforms in the public sector has been a relaxation of the focus on inputs (line item budgeting) to a focus on outputs and outcomes. But the culture of close, quantified control has remained; it has simply been transferred to output and outcome reporting. The implicit assumption behind such a reporting burden is that it is only through a set of explicit controls that performance can be guaranteed. If there had been some general failure by governments to deliver better outcomes in education, health or road safety, then such attention would be warranted. But there is no such evidence. Evidence from the US, in fact, suggests that with the possible exception of crime there has been consistent and long established improvement in outcomes which are influenced by government policy - road safety, health, literacy and many other areas.(16) Improvement didn't wait until Al Gore decided to read Osborne and Gaebler's cult epistle on "reinventing government".(17) Outcome improvement was going on long before the peddlers of prophetic hype and managementspeak were born.

Trying to achieve efficiency improvement through explicit controls is ultimately self-defeating, for the costs of those controls (what economists refer to as "transaction costs") soon outweigh any improvements resulting from their imposition. There are other possible paths to reform, such as building trust in institutions. The alternative of developing and encouraging higher trust and a sense of responsibility, however, seems to be quaintly old-fashioned. As Francis Fukuyama points out, trust is an asset which reduces the transaction costs (or "paperwork" in everyday language) of control.(18) Specifically referring to the public sector Micklethwait and Wooldridge, citing the ideas of Henry Mintzberg, point out that "civil service professions have traditionally exercised control through shared values, inculcated through long training; now it is assumed that their only values are financial."(19)

Trust in institutions is one of the casualties of the "reforms". The Australian Taxation Office, for example, in selling ABN records to private banks and accounting firms, has eroded trust. Yet trust is one of the essential ingredients of a well-functioning taxation system. For the sake of a small amount of revenue, which would make its performance bottom line look more pleasing to the bean counters, the Tax Office has eroded one its prime assets.

Performance measurement is intrinsically complex, but such complexity is brushed aside in the push for governments to develop indicators of efficiency, effectiveness, outputs and outcomes. Such terms are bandied about by people with little knowledge of the complexity inherent in such measures. Eminent economists, such as George Stigler, have warned that even the seemingly simple concept of technical efficiency may be meaningless.(20) If "efficiency dividends" are produced through extra unpaid overtime, or a deferral of annual leave, this is hardly an improvement in efficiency; rather it's a case of working harder, not smarter. Substituting capital for labor may increase labour productivity, but in the public service it has necessarily increased efficiency, as measured by more complex (but still partial) measures such as total factor productivity.(21)

One of the most inappropriate institutions in the public service has been individual performance-based pay. In a survey of senior public servants, performance based pay was found to be one of the least well accepted "reforms".(22) Well-accepted management research suggests that performance-based pay is not a guaranteed motivator. For people who are intrinsically motivated, perhaps through loyalty to a professional set of standards, extrinsic rewards such as performance based pay will generally be seen as patronising and devaluing, thus decreasing their motivation.(23) It is not only wasteful; it is also de-motivating to some of the most enthusiastic and professional staff.

But perhaps professional standards are incompatible with the new managerialism. Self-starters and enthusiastic staff are less malleable than myrmidons who will respond, in true Pavlovian style, to the caprices of political opportunism. At the time of writing, the head of the Department and Cabinet was proposing to increase senior executive salaries to the half million dollar range.(24) Such a proposal begs one to question what has changed in the public service that it can no longer attract trusted, competent and dedicated people as it has in the past; perhaps it has become a very unattractive place for such people to work.

Contracting out

Finally, there is the "reform" of competitive tendering and contracting out. The justifications are in terms of opening up services to competitive contestability, allowing agencies to retreat to specialize in their core competencies, and obtaining the benefits to be found in best private sector practice.

Evidence on the success of contracting out, however, is mixed. When it comes to simply specified services, such as trash collection and cleaning, contracting out seems to result in cost savings; for more complex activities, however, there is no firm evidence of cost saving and some evidence of reduction in quality.(25)

Certainly the Commonwealth has bent over backwards to help potential private sector contractors. In the Commercial Support Program of the Defence Department, for example, the government actually publishes its cost estimates for standard components, such as hourly labour rates, using costing methods which tend to overstate the government's costs because they include full overhead absorption. All the private competitors have to do is to come in below the inflated internal estimates.

Similarly the Commonwealth is divesting itself of property ownership. It has signalled that it will sell buildings to the private sector, and lease them back, unless the return required by the private owners is too high - "too high" in this case being an annual return of 20 percent.(26) It has sold custom built buildings, just for the sake of reducing reported debt. To take a domestic analogy, imagine selling your house and renting it back, just so you could say you had paid off your mortgage. If your mortgage had been at, say, 8 percent and the new owner was getting a 19 percent return, this would hardly be an intelligent move. But that is just what is advocated, and practised, by the Commonwealth, in the name of reducing debt.

While some contracting out results in a private sector windfall, some benefits no-one, other than lawyers and accountants. There is little, if any, accountability for the transaction costs associated with contracting out through competitive tender. These costs include preparing specifications, selecting tenderers, handling legal complaints of unsuccessful tenderers, and supervising contracts. (Ironically, such costs are often counted as "corporate overheads", and have to be absorbed by internal business units competing for government work.) Nor is there any public accountability for the costs borne by unsuccessful tenderers, which are usually passed on in terms of higher prices when they do eventually win government contracts.

Contracting out is often justified on a "core business" argument. The notion that organizations should retreat to a set of core activities, however, is based on a misunderstanding of management theory. Organizations with many activities exist precisely because the control systems within organizations minimize transaction costs and allow for a high degree of flexibility. To take another domestic analogy, most people own a car, even though they are not specialized drivers. The alternative of using taxis for all travel is unacceptable, because of the loss of flexibility and the cost of booking cabs and handling the monetary transactions.

In the public service, in fact, the whole notion of core business is, in fact, somewhat elusive. Market failure does not follow neat, compartmentalized forms. Many disparate activities end up in the public sector - as Herbert Leonard of Harvard's Kennedy School says "the hard jobs are left to the public sector". Government departments are therefore grab-bags of loosely connected activities. Some large activities, such a s Medicare claims processing, can be separately identified, but there are many small, residual functions. That is the nature of government. McDonalds may be able to decide it will restrict itself to fast food and stay out of the gourmet end of the market, but Customs cannot decide it is going to stick to import processing and give up drug interception because it's too difficult and costly. (That is one reason why techniques such as continuous improvement, which apply to mass production functions, are not particularly suited to most government functions.)

Contracting out leads to a long term loss of competencies in the public service. Once functions are contracted out all that remains is a group of contract managers, who have no more than low level generic managerial skills, and who are incapable of assessing the technical aspects of tenders and contracts. The Institution of Engineers has commented on the "de-engineering" of the public service - engineering and technical jobs have been stripped out of public sector agencies. When they have been replaced they have been replaced by "managers", lacking in technical skills.(27) Similarly, many competent policy analysts have been lost to the public sector, and have been taken on by consulting firms which contract to the government. This imposes high transaction costs, for the fees charged by the consulting firm have to cover tendering costs, and the consultants are generally on a learning curve for each new job - working on sports administration last month, foreign policy this month, and aged care next month. The assets of specialization, continuity and personal experience have been lost.

In all the rhetoric on contracting out there has been a good deal of faith put into the benefits of competitive contestability.(28) There has been virtually no discussion on the alternative, and that is internal reform. The implication seems to be that public service managers are too incompetent to improve the performance of their own work units. No one who has managed in the public sector would deny that reform is difficult, but is this because of some intrinsic incompetence? More likely, it is because of government imposed costs and restrictions - heavy paperwork in the name of "accountability", the provision of political support for executive government, requirements to use private sector services rather than developing in-house expertise, and financial regulations which sacrifice performance to the achievement of impressive short term financial reports. These encumber the manager who wants to bring about genuine reform, and there is no shortage of private sector competitors who have a vested interest in seeing that the public sector remains encumbered.

Conclusion

A professional public service is a valuable asset. We come to appreciate it, perhaps, only when we observe the effects of its demise.

In the name of "reform" there has been a large amount of damage done to Australia's public service. While some of the reforms have had grounding in good management practice, many have not. Many have become intertwined with the barren ideology of reducing the size of government. Some have tried to emulate private sector practices, without appreciating the context within which those practices apply.

Australia needs to build a normative model of public service. For a long time that model was implicit in an unwritten contract between executive government and the public service, but there is nothing left of that contract, and, apart from some vague and inappropriate notion of competitive contestability, nothing has replaced it. There is a sound, rational, set of economic theory that defines a role for the public sector in a market economy, but that theory is not within the guiding principles of the new public service. That omission is costly, for the result is ultimately impoverished economic and social policy.


References

1. MAB/MMIAC Beyond Beancounting - Effective Financial Management in the ABS - 1998 and beyond (AGPS 1997).

2. Accrual Budgeting Project http://www.dofa.gov.au/abp/new_framework/framework.html

3. H Thomas Johnson and Robert S Kaplan Relevance Lost: The Rise and fall of Management Accounting (Harvard Business School press 1987).

4. Michael Pusey Economic Rationalism in Canberra (Canbridge University press 1991).

5. Tony Harris "Auditors-General: Policies and Politics" Speech on Friday 19 May 200, Main Committee Room, Parliament House, Canberra.

6. Peter Drucker The Practice of Management (Harper and Row 1954).

7. Peter Drucker "Really Reinventing Government" Atlantic Monthly February 1995.

8. Alistair Mant Intelligent Leadership (Allen & Unwin 1997).

9. K C Where The Civil Service in the Constitution - A lecture delivered before the University of London on 16 February 1954 to commemorate the centenary of the Northcote-Trevelyan Report. (University of London, Athlone press, 1954)

10. Public Service and Merit Protection Commission Mobility in the Australian Public Service (PSMPC 1977).

11. A W Martin "Menzies the Man" in Scott Prasser, John Nethercote (eds) The Menzies Era (Hale & Ironmnoger 1995)

12. There are numerous writings defending the traditional role of the public service. See, for example, Alan S Blinder "Is Government Too Political" in Foreign Affairs November/December 1997, or Robert Reich "Policy Making in a Democracy" in Robert Reich (ed) The Power of Public Ideas (Ballinger 1998).

13. Mancur Olson The Rise and Decline of Nations (Yale University Press 1982).

14. William T Gormley "The Bureaucracy and its Masters: The New Madisonian System in the US" Governance Vol 4 # 1 January 1991.

15. John Micklethwait and Adrian Wooldridge The Witch Doctors (Mandarin UK 1997) p. 328.

16. Joseph S Nye; Philip D Zelinkow,; David King Why people Don't Trust Government (Harvard University Press 1997.)

17. David Osborne and Ted Gaebler Reinventing Government: How the Entrepreneurial Spirit is Transforming the Public Sector (Addison Wesley 1992)

18. Francis Fukuyama Trust (Free press 1995)

19. Micklethwait and Wooldridge op. cit. p. 330.

20. George Stigler "The Xistence of X-efficiency" American Economic Review Vol 66 # 1 March 1976.

21. George Verikios "Estimating Productivity in Government Administration Services in Australia" Economic Papers, Vol 17 # 2 June 1998.

22. John Halligan, Ian Mackintosh, Hugh Watson The Australian Public Service: the view from the top (Coopers and Lybrand and University of Canberra 1996).

23. Edward Deci and Richard Ryan Intrinsic Motivation and Self-Determination in Human Behavior (Plenum Press 1985)

24. Mike Taylor "PS plan targets private sector executives" Canberra Times 6 November 1998.

25. Graeme Hodge Contracting out government services - a review of international evidence (Montech Pty Ltd (Monash University) 1996).

26. Commonwealth Department of Finance, Domestic Property Task Force Report August 1996.

27. Athol Yates Government as an informed buyer: Recognising technical expertise as a crucial factor in the success of engineering contracts.) Institution of Engineers, Australia, 2000 http://www.ieaust.org.au)

28. National Commission of Audit op. cit.